Monday, November 7, 2016

PART 1; THE TRUE HISTORY OF THE AMERICAN REVOLUTION

 THE TRUE HISTORY OF THE AMERICAN REVOLUTION
Image result for images from THE TRUE HISTORY OF THE AMERICAN REVOLUTION
By Sydney George Fisher

Preface 
THE purpose of this history of the Revolution is to use the original authorities rather more frankly than has been the practice with our historians. They appear to have thought it advisable to omit from their narratives a great deal which, to me, seems essential to a true picture. 

I cannot feel satisfied with any description of the Revolution which treats the desire for independence as a sudden thought, and not a long growth and development, or which assumes that every detail of the conduct of the British government was absurdly stupid, even from its own point of view, and that the loyalists were few in numbers and their arguments not worth considering. I cannot see any advantage in not describing in their full meaning and force the smuggling, the buying of laws from the governors, and other irregular conduct in the colonies which led England to try to remodel them as soon as the fear of the French in Canada was removed. Nor can I accept a description which fails to reveal the salient details of the great controversy over the rather peculiar methods adopted by General Howe to suppress the rebellion. This controversy was a part of the Revolution. It involved the interesting question of Howe's instructions from the ministry and the methods which the ministry intended to use with the revolted colonists. 

Whatever we may now think of Howe's conduct, and in whatever way we may try to explain it, the fact remains that it was once a subject which attracted universal attention and aroused most violent attacks upon him in England and among the loyalists in America. Some of these very plain-spoken arraignments, with the evidence in support of them, can still be read in the writings of Galloway, Van Schaack, and others, or in Howe's own defense, which some thought was the strongest argument against him. Why should these documents and the evidence taken before the Parliamentary committee of inquiry he concealed from the ordinary reader, with the result that if by chance he turns to the original authorities he is surprised to find that the Revolution there described is entirely different from the one in which he had been taught to believe ?

Some of us might possibly not accept these attacks upon Howe as just or well founded ; they might think that his reply, which we can still read in his published "Narrative," was a complete defense and justification. There is no reason why we should not adopt any opinion or explanation which seems best. But I protest against the historians who refuse to give us a chance to form an opinion of our own on either the one side or the other. I protest against the concealing of this subject, of suppressing the whole of the evidence against Howe as well as the evidence in his favor ; and I protest because his conduct necessarily produced momentous results in the Revolution.

To my mind the whole question of the conduct of General Howe is as important a part of history as the assistance rendered us by France ; for if what the people of his own time said of Howe be true, his conduct directly contributed to bring about our alliance with that country, and ultimately our independence. 

There has, it seems, been a strong temptation to withhold from the modern public a knowledge of the controversy over Howe's conduct, because it is impossible to disclose that controversy in all its bearings without at the same time showing that the British government, up to the summer of 1778, used extremely lenient and conciliatory methods in dealing with the revolted colonists. The historians appear to have felt that to admit that such gentle methods were used would be inadvisable, would tend to weaken our side of the argument, and show that we were bent on independence for mere independence' sake.

The historians seem to have assumed that we do not want to know about that controversy, or that it will be better for us not to know about it. They have assumed that it will be better for Americans to think that independence was a sudden and deplorable necessity and not a desire of long and ardent growth and cautiously planned intention. They have assumed that we want to think of England as having lost the colonies by failure to be conciliatory, and that the Revolution was a one-sided, smooth affair, without any of the difficulties or terrors of a rebellion or a great upheaval of settled opinion. 

The taint of these assumptions runs through all our histories. They are, I think, mistaken assumptions and an affront to our people. They prefer to know the truth, and the whole truth ; and there is nothing in the truth of which they need be afraid.

Having decided to withhold from the public a knowledge of the contemporary opinion of Howe, the historians naturally conceal or obscure his relations to the Whig party, the position of that party in England, its connection with the rebel colonists, the peculiar difficulties under which the Tory ministry labored, and their instructions to Howe on the conduct of the war. Unless all these conditions are clearly set forth, most of the events and battles of the Revolution are inexplicable. 

Before I discovered the omissions of our standard histories I always felt as though I were reading about something that had never happened, and that was contrary to the ordinary experience of human nature. I could not understand how a movement which was supposed to have been such a deep uprooting of settled thought and custom a movement which is supposed to have been one of the great epochs of history could have happened like an occurrence in a fairy-tale. I could not understand the military operations ; and it seemed strange to me that they were not investigated, explained, and criticized like those of Napoleon's campaigns or of our own Civil War.

I was never satisfied until I had spent a great deal of time in research, burrowing into the dust of the hundreds of old brown pamphlets, newspapers, letters, personal memoirs, documents, publications of historical societies, and the interminable debates of Parliament which, now that the eye-witnesses are dead, constitute all the evidence that is left us of the story of the Revolution. Those musty documents painted a very vivid picture upon my mind, and I wish I had the power of painting the picture as the original sources reveal it.

I understand, of course, that the methods used by our historians have been intended to be productive of good results, to build up nationality, and to check sectionalism and rebellion. Students and the literary class do not altogether like successful rebellions ; and the word revolution is merely another name for a successful rebellion. Rebellions are a trifle awkward when you have settled down, although the Declaration of Independence contains a clause to relieve this embarrassment by declaring that " governments long established should not be changed for light or transient causes." The people who write histories are usually of the class who take the side of the government in a revolution ; and as Americans they are anxious to believe that our Revolution was different from others, more decorous, and altogether free from the atrocities, mistakes, and absurdities which characterize even the patriot party in a revolution. They do not like to describe in their full coloring the strong Americanism and the doctrines of the rights of man which inspired the party that put through our successful rebellion. They have accordingly tried to describe a revolution in which all scholarly, refined, and conservative persons might have unhesitatingly taken part; but such revolutions have never been known to happen.

The Revolution was a much more ugly and unpleasant affair than most of us imagine. I know of many people who talk a great deal about their ancestors, but who I am. quite sure would not now take the side their ancestors chose. Nor was it a great, spontaneous, unanimous uprising, all righteousness, perfection, and infallibility, a marvel of success at every step, and incapable of failure, as many of us very naturally believe from what we have read.

The device of softening the unpleasant or rebellious features of the Eevolution does not, I think, accomplish the improving and edifying results among us, which the historians from their exalted station are so gracious as to wish to bestow. A candid and free disclosure of all that the records contain would be more appreciated by our people and of more advantage to them. They are as fully competent to judge of actions and events as any one of their number who takes upon himself the tasks of the historian, 

It will be observed that I invariably speak of those colonists who were opposed to the rebellion as loyalists, and not as Tories. They never fully accepted the name Tory, either in its contemptuous sense or as meaning a member of the Tory party in England. They were not entirely in accord with that party. They regarded themselves as Americans who were loyal to what they called the empire, and this distinction was, in their minds, of vast importance. I have labored to describe them strictly from their own point of view, with the arguments, facts, principles, and feelings which they used in their pamphlets and documents ; and I give them the name which they preferred. They were far more numerous than is generally supposed; and on the difficult question of their numbers I shall give my readers the advantage of all that I can find in the records. 

In the illustrations of this volume I have for the most part avoided reproductions of portraits, because they are apt to be misleading. I have given, however, the portraits of two loyalists, whose fine clothes do not perhaps misrepresent them. We can have faith in very few of the Revolutionary portraits as likenesses ; and the handsome clothes or magnificent uniforms in which it was easy enough to paint patriot officers, and the modern illustrator's efforts to produce elegance or quaintness, are altogether inconsistent with the agitation, ragged poverty, suffering, and apparent hopelessness which marked one of the most remarkable political outbursts of history.

The True History of the 
American Revolution
1.
 EARLY CONDITIONS AND CAUSES
THE great underlying conditions which brought about the Revolution were the presence of the French in Canada, and the extremely liberal governments, semi-independence, and disregard of laws and regulations which England, in the early days, was compelled to allow the colonies in America. The increasing power of France in the north compelled England to be liberal and even lax in governing her colonies. As tho, attitude of France became more and more threatening down to the year 1763, England could take no severe or repressive measures with the Americans, who were growing up very much as they pleased. 

In our time colonies usually are regarded as places for the overflow of the mother country's excess of population. But down to the time of our Revolution England had no overflow of population. When England began to have colonies in America, about the year 1610, her population was only five million. At the time of our Revolution it was barely eight million, and large districts of country, especially in the northern part of England, were still almost as primitive and uncultivated as the American wilderness.

Colonies were in early times regarded as places for obtaining gold; silver, and furs ; and it was hoped that if people could be forced to go out to them they might be able to extend trade, furnish England raw material, and create a market for manufactured goods. The people who settled in America were either mere adventurous characters, like the first "Virginia colonists, or Puritans, Quakers, and Roman Catholics driven out of England by the severity of royalists and churchmen, or they were royalists, like those of the second migration to Virginia, driven out of England when the Puritans under Cromwell got into power.

When persecution ceased there was no migration of any importance to the colonies. Migration to New England ceased after 1640; and in all the colonies the migration was comparatively small. The people increased in the natural way by births, and increased with remarkable rapidity. The two million, white colonists of 1776 were largely a native stock, whose ancestors had been on the soil for many generations ; and they had grown out of an original stock of immigrants which had not numbered one hundred thousand.* This native and natural growth is worth remembering when we are seeking to explain the desire for independence.
* F. B. Dexter, u Estimates of Population in the American. Colonies/' p. 29, published by the American Antiquarian Society
Alluring promises of gold and easy systems of government were the great persuasions to English colonization. The British government, only too glad to be rid of rebellious Puritans, Quakers, and Roman Catholics, willingly gave them liberal charters. This explains that freedom in many of the old charters which has surprised so many students of our colonial history. Some of these liberal instruments were granted by the Stuart kings, with the approval of their officials and courtiers, all of whom showed by almost every other act of their lives that they were the determined enemies of free parliaments and free representation of the people.

Connecticut, for example, obtained in 1662 from Charles II. a charter which made the colony almost independent and to-day there is no colony of the British empire that has so much freedom as Connecticut and Rhode Island always had, or as Massachusetts had down to 1685. Connecticut and Rhode Island elected their own legislatures and governors, and did not even have to send their laws to England for approval.* No modern British colony elects its own governor and, if it has a legislature elected by its people, the acts of that legislature can be vetoed by the home government. A community electing its own governor and enacting whatever laws it pleases is not a colony in the modern English meaning of the word. Connecticut and Rhode Island could not make treaties with foreign nations, but in other respects they were, as we would now say, semi-independent commonwealths under the protectorate or suzerainty of England.+ 
* The charters can be read in the collections of Poore or of Hazzard. See Palfrey, " New England, " vol. ii. pp. 540, 566. 

+ Neither Connecticut nor Rhode Island changed its form of government during the Revolution. The Connecticut charter was found to be liberal enough to serve as the constitution of an American State ; and Connecticut lived under it until 1818. Rhode Island lived under her charter as a constitution until 1842.

The obtaining of this extremely liberal Connecticut charter has sometimes been explained by suggesting that Winthrop, who went to England to procure it, had money to distribute among courtiers. A pretty story is also told of his having a ring which had been given to his father by Charles I. ; and this ring, when shown to Charles II., is supposed to have worked the miracle of the liberal charter.

But the liberality is more easily accounted for by the desire of the British government to encourage planting, as it was called, and get rid of rebellious and troublesome people. England had not then made up her mind exactly what she meant by a colony, except that she was anxious to have people go out and settle on the wild land in America which was hers by right of discovery. The year after the Connecticut charter was granted Rhode Island obtained a liberal charter, almost word for word the same as the charter of Connecticut ; and the agent in that case was the Rev. John Clark, a Baptist minister of the gospel, who had no money and no ancestral ring.

Some thirty years before that time Massachusetts had obtained a liberal charter. It was possibly intended that the governing body under this charter should remain in England; but the Puritans who had obtained it moved the whole governing body out to Massachusetts, elected their own legislature and governor, and did not submit their laws to England for approval. They assumed several of the attributes of sovereignty. They coined their own money, and issued the famous pine-tree shilling. They established by law a form of religion, sometimes called Congregationalism, which was-; not recognized by the laws of England. They ceased to issue writs in the king's name. They dropped the English oath of allegiance and adopted a new oath in which public officers and the people swore allegiance, not to England, but to Massachusetts. 

They debated what allegiance they owed to England, and concluded that they were independent in government, that no appeals could be taken to England, but that they were under an English protectorate. When some captains of vessels reminded them that no English flag was displayed in the colony, they debated whether the British flag should be allowed to fly on the fort at Castle Island, and concluded that it might be put there, as that particular fort was the king's property. But they had given so little attention to allegiance and the symbol of it that at the close of this debate no English flags could be found in Boston, and they had to borrow one from the captain of a ship.*
* Winthrop's Journal, published as the "History of New England, vol. i. pp. 187, 188; vol. ii. pp. 279, 282 j Palfrey, "New England," vol. i, pp. 284, 375, 499, et passim.
Under the charter which allowed so much freedom Massachusetts existed from 1629 to 1685, when her disregard of British authority and the killing, whipping, and imprisoning of Quakers and Baptists had reached such a pass that the charter was annulled, and Massachusetts became a colony, with a governor appointed by the king, and controlled in a way which, after her previous freedom, was very galling.

These instances show why New England was so hot for independence from 1764 to 1776. Virginia was also ardent, and there, too, we find that an extremely liberal government had been allowed to grow up. Virginia had, alone and single-handed, in 1676, rebelled against the whole authority of the British government, because she thought her privileges were being impaired. Such an outbreak as this and a similar rebellion in Massachusetts in 1690 warned England to be as gentle as possible with the colonies, while France was becoming more and more of a power on the north and west. 

The other colonies never had so much freedom. None of them elected their own governors ; they had not had such a taste of independence as New England and Virginia, which from the English point of view were regarded as the leaders in rebellion. But they had all had a certain measure of their own way of doing things, and had struggled to have more of their own way, and had found that England was compelled at times to yield to them. It is not necessary to describe the details of this struggle, its successes or failures. It is of more importance to describe a method of government which grew up in all the colonies that did not elect their own governors, a method which they regarded as the bulwark of their liberties, which in England was regarded as scandalous, and which had an important influence on the Revolution.

It arose out of the system by which the people of the colony elected the legislature, and the crown, or a proprietor under the crown, as in Pennsylvania and Maryland, appointed the governor. Under this system the legislature voted the governor his salary out of taxes which all these colonial legislatures had the power of levying. The governor had the power of absolute veto on all acts of the legislature, and, as representing the crown, he wanted certain laws passed to carry out the ideas or reforms of the home government.

The members of the legislature cared little or nothing for these reforms. As representing the people, they had their popular measures which they wished carried out. These measures the governor usually wanted to veto, either because he deemed them hostile to the interests of the crown, or because he wished to punish the legislature for failing to pass crown measures on which his reputation at home depended.

The governor and the legislature being thus dependent on each other, the question of salary throw the balance of power into the hands of the legislature. They quickly learned the trick of withholding the governor's salary until he had assented to their measures. The system became practically one of bargain and sale, as Franklin called it. The people, through their legislators, bought from the governor, for cash, such laws as they needed. The petty squabbles with the governor, based on the detailed working of the system, were interminable in every colony where it prevailed. They fill the minute books and records, making colonial history more tiresome than it might otherwise be, except in one instance, where Franklin, who often came in contact with the system, described it in his inimitable manner:

" Hence arose the custom of presents twice a year to the governors, at the close of each session in which laws were passed, given at the time of passing ; they usually amounted to a thousand pounds per annual. But when the governors and assemblies disagreed, so that laws were not passed, the presents were withheld. When a disposition to agree ensued, there sometimes still remained some diffidence. The governors would not pass the laws that were wanted without "being sure of the money, even all that they called their arrears ; nor the assemblies give the money without being sure of the laws. Thence the necessity of some private conference, in which mutual assurances of good faith might he received and given, that the transaction should go hand in hand. "What name the impartial reader will give to this kind of commerce I cannot say. . . . Time established the custom and made it seem honest ; so that our governors, even those of the most undoubted honor, have practiced it. ... 

" 'When they came to resolve, on the report of the grand committee, to give the money, they guarded their resolves very cautiously, to wit : ' Resolved that on the passage of such bills as now lie before the governor (the naturalization bill and such other bills as may be presented to him during the sitting) there be paid him the sum of five hundred pounds.' . . .

 " Do not, my.courteous reader, take pet at our proprietary constitution for these our bargain and sale proceedings in legislation. It is a happy country where justice and what was your own before can be had for ready money. It is another addition to the value of money, and, of course, another spur to industry. Every land is not so blessed,   Works, Bigelow edition, vol. iii. pp. 311-316.

What was thought and said of this system depended entirely on one's point of view. Franklin ridiculed it when it worked against him. Afterwards, in the Revolution, when he saw that colonial self-government depended upon it, he became, like Dickinson and other patriot leaders, a stanch upholder of it* In England it was regarded as corruption. There was plenty of corruption in England at that time ; but outside corruption always seems the more heinous ; and this particular corruption blocked and thwarted nearly all the plaus of the mother country to regulate her colonies. It was believed to have seriously interfered with the raising of supplies and aids for the war against the French and Indians. If anything of the sort existed in our time, if a territory of the United States, or an island like Porto Rico, were governed in that way, we would denounce it as most atrocious and absurd ; and in all probability put a stop to it very quickly. It was very natural that England, acting from her point of view, should start to abolish it as soon ay France was driven from the continent, and this attempt was one of the fundamental causes of the Revolution.
* Franklin, "Works, Bigolow edition, vol. iv. pp. 407, 4M j vol. v. p. 465. Dickinson describes tho advantages of the system iu his "Letters from a Farmer, 7 ' letters ix., x., etc.

The colonists who had become Americanized, tinged with the soil, differentiated from English influence, or, as Englishmen said, rebelliously inclined, were all enthusiastic supporters of the bargain and sale system. They loved it and were ready to die for it, and resisted any change or reform in it. They would not hear of fixing regular salaries upon the governors, because they knew that the moment the governors ceased to be dependent on the legislatures for their salaries, the legislatures would be powerless to accomplish the popular will, and the colonies, except Connecticut and Rhode Island, would fall completely under control of Parliament and the king. Each legislature was called and adjourned by the governor; and he would hardly take the trouble to call it ? except to pass crown measures, unless he was dependent on it for his salary.

In every colony where this system prevailed there was a body of popular laws on the statute-book which, in the course of fifty or a hundred years, had been secured, one by one, by this bargaining with the governor. The people, who were patriotically inclined, loved these laws; and had enjoyed the contests for them. They had heard and read the details of these contests at the taverns and coffeehouses; the self-confident, haughty, or scolding messages of the governor, and the astute or sarcastic replies of the legislature ; and they fought the wordy battle over again with keen interest. So long as they controlled the governor's salary they felt themselves freemen ; once lose that control, and they were, as they expressed it, political slaves.

The system extended to the judges, who, though appointed by the crown or governor, were dependent for their salaries on the annual vote or whim of the legislature. In New York the judiciary was believed to be notoriously dependent. A chief justice, it was said, gave a decision against a member of the legislature, who promptly, in retaliation, had the judge's salary reduced fifty pounds. The local magistrates in New York were controlled by the assemblymen. Some of these magistrates could not write, and had to affix their marks to warrants. * 
* "Documents relating to the Colonial History of New York," vol. vii. pp. 500, 705, 760, 774, 796, 797, 906, 979
The colonists insisted that they must retain control of the judges' salaries, because, if the crown both appointed the judges and paid them their salaries, the decisions would all be crown decisions. They were willing to compromise, however, and fix permanent salaries on the judges if the home government would agree that the judges should be appointed for life and good behavior instead of holding office at the pleasure of the crown. This apparently reasonable suggestion the English government would not adopt* They seem to have feared that the judges appointed by that tenure would gradually drift to the side of the colonists, and make regulation and administration more difficult than ever. It was already extremely difficult to get a jury to decide in favor of the crown. The control of the colonies seemed to be slipping away, and the ministry must retain as much of it as was possible.
 * Franklin, "Works, Bigelow edition, vol, v, pp. 408, 404
Those acts of Parliament by which the money raised from taxes on the colonies was not to be cast generally into the English exchequer, but to be used for "defraying the expenses of government and the administration of justice in the colonies," and therefore would be all spent in the colonies, read innocently enough. What could be more fair and honorable towards you, Englishmen would say, than an act which takes no money out of your country ? It is the same money which you now raise by taxing yourselves ; it will be spent, in the same way as you apply it, to pay governors and judges, and on a fixed and regular system.

But the " fixed and regular system" destroyed what the Americans considered their fundamental, constitutional principle, by which executive salaries must be within popular control. That principle was vitally necessary to all the colonies, except to Connecticut and Rhode Island. It would become vital to Connecticut and Rhode Island if they should lose the right to elect their own governors, as was not improbable when England began her remodeling after the expulsion of France from Canada.

One effect of the system was to divide the upper classes of the colonists, and indeed all the people, into two parties, those who were interested in the governor and the executive officers, and those who were interested in the legislature. Around every governor appointed from England there grew up a little aristocracy of powerful families and individuals, with their patronage, influence, and branches extending down through all classes. The people of this party who had means and education considered themselves the social superiors, because they were most closely connected with England and the king, who was the source of all rank and nobility. They considered themselves the only American society that deserved recognition. Nearly all of them became loyalists in the Revolution.

Among the legislative party, as it may be called, there were individuals and families of as much means and as good education as any in the governor's or executive party. But they formed a set by themselves, and were sometimes hardly on speaking terms with the executive party. In some of the colonies the two parties were on friendly terms ; but in Pennsylvania, New York, and Massachusetts the contests and hatred between them were, at times, extremely bitter and violent. 

Prominent men whose names have become household words among us Hancock, Adams, and Warren, of Massachusetts, Schuyler, Hamilton, and Livingston, of New York, Eeed, Morris, Dickinson, and Mifflin, of Pennsylvania, Paca and Chase, of Maryland, and Lee, Washington, Bland, and Harrison, of Virginia were all of the Whig legislative set They were more or less distinctly separated from the high society that basked in the regal sunlight which, even when filtered through a colonial governor, was supposed to redeem America from vulgarity.

Had the Revolution terminated differently, another class of names might be household words in America, Hunt, Galloway, Allen, and Hamilton, of Pennsylvania, DeLancey, Van Schaack, and Jones, of New York, Leonard, Sewall, Curwen, and Oliver, of Massachusetts, names which once filled a large place in the public vision, but which now are meaningless to nearly every one. 

England's easy method of dealing with her colonies had certainly produced a confused and irregular state of affairs, which was worse than has yet been described. It is important for us to remember many of the details of this condition, because they show the beginning of English dissatisfaction with the colonies and of the desire to have a sweeping remodeling as soon as Franco was out of the way. 

The colonies, in exercise of the extreme liberty that had been allowed them, had taken on themselves to create their own paper currency. In some of them, especially in Now England, the paper currency was very seriously depreciated. In Pennsylvania the currency never depreciated ; * but this did not help matters, because conservative people in England would regard it as merely a delusive encouragement of an evil system. 
* " Pennsylvania : Colony and Commonwealth, pp. 72, 80, 87; Phillips, u Historical Sketches of Paper Currency in the American Colonies."
This paper money the colonists considered absolutely necessary to supply the place of the gold and silver which were so rapidly drained from them into England to pay for the manufactured goods they bought. There seems to be no doubt but that they were right in this, 'and so long as the issues of paper money were kept within safe bounds,as in Pennsylvania, no harm resulted. But there were such disastrous results in other colonies that there was a great outcry in England. To many Englishmen this paper money seemed to be a mere dishonorable device to avoid paying the heavy debts which the colonists owed to the British merchants, who sold to them the axes with which they felled the forests, the ploughs with which they tilled the land, and the utensils in which they cooked their dinners. 

This opinion was strengthened when it was remembered that some British colonies had attempted to pass stay laws to prevent English merchants from collecting debts, and that this risk had to be removed by an act of Parliament in 1732, giving English merchants the same right to seize private property for debt in the colonies that they had in England.* Finally, in 1751, Parliament tried to remedy the paper money evil, and passed an act declaring the paper money of the New England colonies an illegal tender in payment of a debt. 
* "The Interest of the Merchants and Manufacturers of Great Britain in the Present Contest with the Colonies," p. 38, London, 1774.
Good people in England and many members of Parliament looked upon the whole revolutionary movement as merely an attempt of debt-ridden provincials to escape from their obligations+ A nation on a firm gold basis always despises a nation struggling with a depreciated currency. We ourselves have had this feeling towards the West Indian and South American republics. 
+ Franklin, Works, Bigelow edition, vol. v. p. 629.

The people in England also heard a great deal about the convicts who had been transported to America, and that some of these convicts had been employed as schoolteachers. Historical writers have given the number of these convicts that were sent here at from ten thousand to twenty-five thousand, most of them going to Maryland and the Middle Colonies.* We may believe that this had no demoralizing effect upon us, and perhaps it had not ; but English people would naturally think that it had tinged our population, and they would exaggerate the evil effects, as we would ourselves if we should hear of twenty thousand convicts dumped into Japan or Cuba, or England itself.
*Scharf, "History of Maryland, 3 ' vol. i. p. 371; Pennsylvania Magazine of History, vol. xii. p. 457.
In early colonial times piracy had been almost openly practiced, and respectable people, even governors of colonies, were interested in its profits. The distinction between privateering, smuggling, piracy, and buccaneering was slight; the step from one to the other easy. The fascinating life ofthese brethren ofthe wave cannot be described here, except to say that piracy had been another item in the list of colonial offences. Protections to pirates were openly sold in New York, where the famous Captain Kidd lived, and handsome presents given to the governor and his daughters. It was a profitable occupation, and pursued as eagerly as modern stock jobbing and speculation. Charleston was equally deep in the business. Lord Bellamont was sent out to New York in 1695, as the result of what we would now call a reform movement. He reported " a most lycencious trade with pirates, Scotland and Curagoa." The people of New York, he said, "grew rich, but the customs, they decrease."
 +  Men, Women, and Manners in Colonial Times, )T vol. ii. pp, 274-285; Johnson, " History of the Pirate;" EHquwuoling, "Buccaneers of America j" " Documents relating to tko Colonial History of New York," index vol., title, " Pirates.''

Piracy, however, had passed away, and it was only a recollection of disorder, part of the ancient training of the colonists in self-will and love of independence. With regard to the other offences, bargain and sale legislation, dependent judiciary, or the reforms and remedies of them, both the colonists and England were in a constrained position so long as France kept strengthening her power on the north and pushing round to the westward into the valleys of the Ohio and the Mississippi.

Kalm, the Swedish botanist, who traveled in America in 1748, reported that the presence of the French in Canada was all that held the colonies in submission to England. He met both Americans and English who prophesied that the colonies would be absolutely independent within thirty or fifty years.*
* " Travels into North America," vol. i. p. 265. 
The more we consider the conditions at that time, the more it becomes evident that the English-speaking communities in America were not colonies in the modern acceptance of the term. England had never fully reduced them to possession, had never really established her sovereignty among them.+ She had encouraged them in the beginning with liberal grants for the sake of persuading them to occupy the country, and after that she was unable to repress their steady and aggressive increase of privileges so long as France hung as a menace in the snow-bound north. The lucky colonists were ridden with a loose rein and given their heads until a large section of them began to believe that their heads were their own. 
+ Dean Tucker said that British sovereignty in the colonies was gone as soon as the French were removed, and that the Kevolution was a contest to recover it. " The True Interest of Great Britain set forth," p. 12, London, 1774j Oartwright's " American Independence the Interest and Glory of Great Britain," pp. 90, 91 j " The Constitutional Bight of the Legislature of Great Britain to tax the British Colonies," p. 8, London, 1768 ; " Letters of Jainos Murray, Loyalist," p. 154 j Franklin, Works, Bigelow edition, vol. iii. p. 144

The colonists, however, needed the assistance of England's army and navy to withstand France. They detested the thought of becoming colonies of the great Celtic and Roman Catholic power ; and they were willing to hold in check their desire for extreme privileges, or anything like independence, until France was removed from the continent. Thus France occupied the peculiar position of encouraging our independent spirit and at the same time checking its extreme development.

"When the great event of her removal was accomplished ; when the superb organizing genius of William Pitt had carried to a successful termination the long war lasting from 1654 to 1763, a totally new condition of affairs arose. Canada being conquered and England in possession of it, the colonies and England suddenly found themselves glaring at each other. Each began to pursue her real purpose more directly. England undertook to establish her sovereignty, abolish abuses, or, as she expressed it at that time, to remodel the colonies. The patriotic party among the colonists resisted the remodelling, sought to retain all their old privileges, and even to acquire new ones.* 
* The change in tho situation was quickly seen by the people of that time. 
" No sooner were tho French kites and tho Indian vulturos scared away than they (tho colonists) began to strut and to claim an independent property to the dunghill. Their fear and tludr natural affection forsook them at one and the same time." "Tho Justus and Necessity of taxing the American Colonies," p. 7, London, 1766. '* Ever since tho reduction of Canada," wrote one of tho ablest of the loyalist pamphleteers, " we have been bloated with u vain opinion of our own importance." "A Friendly Addreaw to all Reasonable Americans," p. 25, New York, 1774. See, also, " Strictures upon tho Declaration of the Congress j" "Observations on the American Revolution, and published by order of Congress, 1770. This document argues that the colonies wore semi-independent states under a protectorate from Great Britain to save thorn from France.

to be continued...next
II SMUGGLING, RIOTING, AND REVOLT AGAINST CONTROL












FAIR USE NOTICE


THIS SITE CONTAINS COPYRIGHTED MATERIAL THE USE OF WHICH HAS NOT ALWAYS BEEN SPECIFICALLY AUTHORIZED BY THE COPYRIGHT OWNER. AS A JOURNALIST, I AM MAKING SUCH MATERIAL AVAILABLE IN MY EFFORTS TO ADVANCE UNDERSTANDING OF ARTISTIC, CULTURAL, HISTORIC, RELIGIOUS AND POLITICAL ISSUES. I BELIEVE THIS CONSTITUTES A 'FAIR USE' OF ANY SUCH COPYRIGHTED MATERIAL AS PROVIDED FOR IN SECTION 107 OF THE US COPYRIGHT LAW.

IN ACCORDANCE WITH TITLE 17 U.S.C. SECTION 107, THE MATERIAL ON THIS SITE IS DISTRIBUTED WITHOUT PROFIT TO THOSE WHO HAVE EXPRESSED A PRIOR INTEREST IN RECEIVING THE INCLUDED INFORMATION FOR RESEARCH AND EDUCATIONAL PURPOSES. COPYRIGHTED MATERIAL CAN BE REMOVED ON THE REQUEST OF THE OWNER.


No comments:

Post a Comment